Minister El-Khatib outlines Egypt's competitive edge for investors    BNY Mellon, HSBC express optimism for Egypt's economy at BEBA mission    Sustained economic reforms drive foreign investment in Egypt – FinMin    Somalia condemns unlawful arms shipment from Ethiopia to Puntland State    Egypt's PM assures no more power cuts, highlights investment growth plans    Egypt's Foreign Minister meets with US lawmakers in Washington    Egypt chairs Khartoum Process meeting on migration, development    Egypt's El-Khatib seeks to boost renewable energy investment with UK companies    Al-Mashat, AfDB Special Envoy discuss development cooperation for Egypt    China imposes sanctions on US arms suppliers to Taiwan    Basketball Africa League Future Pros returns for 2nd season    Google wins EU legal battle over €1.5b fine    Egypt's Environment Minister outlines progress on sustainability initiatives    US examines increased Chinese uranium imports    L'Oréal Egypt Hosts 9th Annual Skin and Hair Summit, Unveils New La Roche-Posay Anti-Pigmentation Serum    Al-Sisi calls for emulating Prophet Muhammad's manners at birth anniversary celebration    Culture Minister directs opening of "Islamic Pottery Museum" to the public on 15 October    Restoration project at Edfu Temple reveals original coloured inscriptions for first time    Egypt joins Africa's FEDA    Egypt's Culture Minister seeks input from Writers Union on national strategy    Egypt awards ZeroCarbon solid waste management contract in Gharbia    Egypt, UN partner on $14-m coral reef protection project    ADB approves $93.6m for Cambodia's rural utilities    Egypt condemns Ethiopia's unilateral approach to GERD filling in letter to UNSC    Egyptian pentathletes dominate world championships in Lithuania    Paris Olympic gold '24 medals hit record value    A minute of silence for Egyptian sports    Egyptian Olympic athletes champion local sportswear    Egypt's FM, Kenya's PM discuss strengthening bilateral ties, shared interests    Paris Olympics opening draws record viewers    Former Egyptian Intelligence Chief El-Tohamy Dies at 77    Who leads the economic portfolios in Egypt's new Cabinet?    Egypt's President assigns Madbouly to form new government    Financial literacy becomes extremely important – EGX official    UNESCO celebrates World Arabic Language Day    Motaz Azaiza mural in Manchester tribute to Palestinian journalists    Russia says it's in sync with US, China, Pakistan on Taliban    It's a bit frustrating to draw at home: Real Madrid keeper after Villarreal game    Shoukry reviews with Guterres Egypt's efforts to achieve SDGs, promote human rights    Sudan says countries must cooperate on vaccines    Johnson & Johnson: Second shot boosts antibodies and protection against COVID-19    Egypt to tax bloggers, YouTubers    Egypt's FM asserts importance of stability in Libya, holding elections as scheduled    We mustn't lose touch: Muller after Bayern win in Bundesliga    Egypt records 36 new deaths from Covid-19, highest since mid June    Egypt sells $3 bln US-dollar dominated eurobonds    Gamal Hanafy's ceramic exhibition at Gezira Arts Centre is a must go    Italian Institute Director Davide Scalmani presents activities of the Cairo Institute for ITALIANA.IT platform    







Thank you for reporting!
This image will be automatically disabled when it gets reported by several people.



Confessions of a financial deregulator
Published in Daily News Egypt on 01 - 07 - 2011

BERKELEY: Back in the late 1990s, in America at least, two schools of thought pushed for more financial deregulation — that is, for repealing the legal separation of investment banking from commercial banking, relaxing banks' capital requirements, and encouraging more aggressive creation and use of derivatives. If deregulation looks like such a bad idea now, why didn't it then?
The first school of thought, broadly that of the United States' Republican Party, was that financial regulation was bad because all regulation was bad. The second, broadly that of the Democratic Party, was somewhat more complicated, and was based on four observations:
• In the global economy's industrial core, at least, it had then been more than 60 years since financial disruption had had more than a minor impact on overall levels of production and employment. While modern central banks had difficulty in dealing with inflationary shocks, it had been generations since they had seen a deflationary shock that they could not handle.
• The profits of the investment-banking oligarchy (the handful of global investment banks, including Goldman Sachs, Morgan Stanley, and JP Morgan Chase, among others) were far in excess of what any competitive market ought to deliver, owing to these banks' deep pockets and ability to maneuver through thickets of regulations.
• The long-run market-return gradient — by which those with deep pockets and the patience to take on real-estate, equity, derivative, and other risks reaped outsize returns — seemed to indicate that financial markets were awful at mobilizing society's risk-bearing capacity.
• The poorer two-thirds of America's population appeared to be shut out of the opportunities to borrow at reasonable interest rates and to invest at high returns that the top third — especially the rich — enjoyed.
These four observations suggested that some institutional experimentation was in order. Depression-era restrictions on risk seemed less urgent, given the US Federal Reserve's proven ability to build firewalls between financial distress and aggregate demand. New ways to borrow and to spread risk seemed to have little downside. More competition for investment-banking oligarchs from commercial bankers and insurance companies with deep pockets seemed likely to reduce the investment banking industry's unconscionable profits.
It seemed worth trying. It wasn't.
Analytically, we are still picking through the wreckage of this experiment.
Why were the risk controls at highly-leveraged money-center universal banks so lousy? Why weren't central banks and governments willing and able to step up and maintain the flow of aggregate demand as the financial crisis and its aftermath choked off private investment and consumption spending?
More questions arise from the policy response to the subsequent recession. Why, once the magnitude of the downturn became clear, weren't governments eager to step in to return unemployment to normal levels, especially in the absence of higher inflation expectations, upward pressure on prices, or even interest-rate increases that would crowd out private investment spending? And how has the financial industry managed to retain so much political power to block regulatory reform?
Moreover, how to restructure the financial system remains unclear. The Glass-Steagall Act's separation of investment from commercial banking greatly benefited the established oligarchy of investment banks, but somehow the entry of competitors from commercial banks and insurers increased financial companies' profits further.
There were significant profit opportunities for financial intermediaries that could find spare risk-bearing capacity, carve out securities to take advantage of it, and thus take a middleman's cut from matching risks with investors who could gain from bearing them. But the advent of derivatives concentrated risk rather than dispersing it, for there was even more money to be made by selling risk to people who did not know how to value it — or, indeed, what risks they were bearing.
And central banks' failure to regard their primary job to be the stabilization of nominal income — their failure not only to be good Keynesians, but even good monetarists — raises the question of whether central banking itself needs drastic reform. Back in 1825, the Bank of England's Governor Cornelius Buller understood that when the private sector had a sudden panic-driven spike in demand for safe and liquid financial assets, it was the Bank's responsibility to meet that demand and so keep bankruptcy and depression at bay. How can his successors know less than he did?
It may even be the case that we ought to return to the much more tightly regulated financial system of the first post-World War II generation. That system served the industrial core well, at least as far as we can tell from the macroeconomic aggregates. We know for certain that our more recent system has not.
J. Bradford DeLong, a former assistant secretary of the US Treasury, is Professor of Economics at the University of California at Berkeley and a research associate at the National Bureau for Economic Research. This commentary is published by Daily News Egypt in collaboration with Project Syndicate, www.project-syndicate.org.


Clic here to read the story from its source.